"The United States and Globalization"
Bruce E. Moon, Lehigh University, USA
Chapter 28 (Part Four: Responses to Globalization)
Richard Stubbs and Geoffrey R.D. Underhill, eds.
. Political Economy and the Changing Global Order
(Oxford University Press, 1998)
Introduction
Most nations can only react to globalization, but the United States, as the system's
dominant economic and political actor, is also able to affect the speed and character of the
globalization process itself. By promoting the institutions that integrated national economies after
World War II, it appears that the U.S. acted as predicted by hegemonic stability theory (HST).(1)
As American dominance faded, the global system drifted away from the coherence of its original
Bretton Woods design to the present chaotic patchwork of inadequate governance, a pattern that
also lends credence to HST explanations centered on the relative decline of the hegemonic power.
However, America's distinctive foreign policy tradition and peculiar political, economic, and
social structure offer a better explanation for the character of the globalization that has emerged.
America's idiosyncratic vision and reluctant hegemony
At the end of World War II, the United States exhibited the two most important
characteristics required of a candidate to champion global liberalism.(2) First, it possessed the
dominance that affords a hegemon both the greatest incentive and the greatest capacity to
advance globalization. As the most productive economy, it was the most likely to benefit from
open goods markets and as the largest source of both supply and demand for capital it was the
most likely to exploit open capital markets. Its power was used to persuade or coopt a majority
of nations, compel most of the remainder, and isolate the few dissenters. Second, the liberalism
of the American domestic economy demonstrated that "its social purpose and domestic
distribution of power was favorably disposed toward a liberal international order".(3) However,
America's dominance is accompanied by a profound isolationism and its liberalism is colored by
its unique circumstances. The effects of these eccentricities were discernible in the Bretton
Woods design but eventually became dominant in both American policy and the global regime it
sponsored.
Hegemonic, but Isolationist
No account of American foreign policy can ignore the monumental shadow cast by the
deep historical isolationism of the United States. From its colonial period onward, America has
displayed hostility to foreign pressures and an abiding antipathy toward multilateral policies and
supra-national institutions.(4) This isolationism has been overcome only occasionally by
extraordinary exigencies, most notably the combination of military, political, and economic
challenges to the immediate postwar order in Europe. Even then, its commitment to a global
institutional order has been reluctant and sporadic, not at all the attitude expected of a hegemon
by HST.
This profound disinterest in foreign affairs has been sustained by a frequently ignored
economic reality: the American economy has been and remains relatively unaffected by
developments elsewhere in the global economy. The historic insulation of the American economy
from the global one stems from the size and physical remoteness of the U.S. market, which relies
less on trade than virtually any other in the world.(5) For most nations, of course, a small foreign
sector would imply proportionately small external influence, but the overwhelming size of the
U.S. market means that even a modest percentage of American GNP constitutes a sizable share of
global economic activity. In the early 1950s, for example, American exports constituted more
than a third of industrial country exports, yet less than 5 percent of U.S. GNP.
This odd pattern of dominance has crosscutting implications for the ability of the U.S. to
embrace its theoretical role of global hegemon. It had the power to shape the international
system's fundamental structure, but little need to do so in order to protect either the national
economy or the interests of sub-national groups. This autonomy allowed the U.S. to be
inattentive to systemic issues and left the system vulnerable to the reemergence of America's
natural isolationism whenever external pressures abated. However, when the U.S. was engaged
with questions of system design, it could easily afford to indulge the interests of others -- as
expected of a hegemon -- because that seldom required much sacrifice of its own modest stake.
Liberal, but myopic
Minimal external reliance also affected the character of American liberalism. With such a
small import-competing sector, protectionist pressures were modest, even though theory identifies
groups that normally oppose free trade. The Stolper-Samuelson theorem predicts that trade
would harm unskilled labor, but that group is notoriously poorly represented by structures of
American political power. Unlike the European working class, which has been championed
economically by a strong trade union movement and defended politically by resultant social
democratic parties, unskilled labor in the U.S. has been divided by ethnic identification, language,
and region, leaving it politically impotent and economically vulnerable. Heckscher-Ohlin trade
theory implies that inefficient sectors of the economy will suffer losses, but the general dominance
of American industry in the immediate postwar era made these niches of comparative advantage
for foreigners hard to find, and, given high transportation costs, difficult to exploit.
As American supremacy has eroded since the 1970s, greater vulnerabilities have produced
dislocations in scattered industries, most prominently in textiles, steel, and autos. But no
ideological current exists to frame these as the inevitable consequences of globalization, and no
organized opposition demands that accommodation be made. Instead, these inroads have been
interpreted as reflections of "cheating" by other nations (especially Japan), triggering a response
in the foreign policy arena rather than an acknowledgment of the trade-offs endemic to an open
economy. In short, U.S. foreign economic policy has a built-in liberal inclination because its
unusually small foreign sector is made up of elements which are either economically invulnerable
to foreign competition or politically powerless to resist it.
As a result, American liberalism, largely unchecked by contrary domestic forces, has become theoretically rigid and ideologically extreme. From Cordell Hull's influential plea for free trade as the key to international peace in the 1940s to American commentary on Russia in the 1990s, U.S. rhetoric has associated free markets with material prosperity, stability, justice, democracy, human rights, international peace and more. As James Fallows puts it:
The Anglo-American system of politics and economics, like any system, rests on
certain principles and beliefs. But rather than acting as if these are the best
principles, or the ones their societies prefer, Britons and Americans often act as if
these were the only possible principles and no one, except in error, could choose
any others. Political economics becomes an essentially religious question, subject
to the standard drawback of any religion -- the failure to understand why people
outside the faith might act as they do.(6)
Herein lies a contradiction. Though a passionate proselytizer, the United States maintains
a more shallow commitment to liberalism than nations whose small market size makes trade
openness inevitable or those for whom it represents a conscious acceptance of its mixed welfare
implications. Nor is it as stable as in those nations where it has evolved as a strategic compromise
among powerful political actors. As a result, American systemic designs are not as attentive to
the complex side-effects of globalization as would be expected from a hegemon more deeply
affected by the system it created.
Bretton Woods
Fifty years ago, the combination of American hegemonic credentials and fortuitous
circumstances were sufficient to fashion a system to meet the delicate balance between national
and systemic needs. At the system's core lie the multilateral trade negotiations of the GATT/ITO,
designed to rekindle economic growth by restoring trade to levels reached before the catastrophic
decline of two-thirds during the Great Depression. However, the key to the success of Bretton
Woods -- and the sharpest contrast with the current system -- was the recognition that
liberalization also brought problems and constraints that not only undermined its benefits but
threatened the capacity of individual nations to embrace it.
The Bretton Woods design acknowledged the sacrifices required of nations in order to
liberalize and contained various provisions for easing those burdens. GATT allowed nations to
demand access to foreign markets for its exports as compensation for the dislocations caused by
imports, thus providing political cover for shaky governments to withstand protectionist pressures
and creating domestic constituencies to balance them. The negotiation process enabled nations to
liberalize trade at a pace compatible with resolving the domestic political and economic problems
it created and GATT itself contained a number of escape clauses that recognized the inherent
tension between liberalization and other domestic economic goals. The IMF not only prescribed
stable exchange rates but also offered resources to member states to facilitate their cooperation in
maintaining them: its lending facilities provided an alternative to exchange rate devaluation and
protectionism for nations feeling balance of payments pressures. Finally, the World Bank offered
longer-term funding to rebuild war-torn economies that otherwise could not survive international
competition, most notably from the United States. American unilateral and bilateral policy toward
Europe, especially the Marshall Plan and the temporary tolerance of European protectionism,
greatly augmented these arrangements, perhaps dwarfing them in effect.
The system as a whole was coherent and realistic, allowing nations to move toward free
capital and goods markets at their own pace. They fashioned arrangements that were consonant
with their own priorities and circumstances but generally reflected "the compromise of embedded
liberalism"(7). The challenge "to devise a form of multilateralism compatible with the requirements
of domestic stability"(8) was not seen as a lofty aspiration, but rather as an absolutely essential
requirement to achieve any kind of workable system at all. Without the flexibility it provided,
nations would neither have agreed to the obligations implicit in acceptance of Bretton Woods
initially nor would they have been capable of meeting them subsequently. At stake was the very
political legitimacy of the state itself, which must not only achieve economic prosperity but also
maintain enough control over the domestic political economy that its claim to being responsive to
the citizenry is seen as plausible.
Still, Bretton Woods, whose sparse institutional component contained no permanent trade
organization, a monetary authority with sharply limited enforcement capacity, and an
underfinanced development bank, represented as minimal a core as could be squared with the
label of "system." If the profound threats of the 1940s made some institutional structure
absolutely imperative, the American influence was responsible for its minimalist character.
Proposals for an IMF and World Bank with a broader charge and expanded powers fell victim to
American antipathy toward intrusive supranational institutions that would challenge U.S. policy
autonomy. During heated negotiations over the charter for the International Trade Organization,
the U.S. blocked provisions that would give the organization greater authority over domestic
economic policies and a larger role in adjudicating trade policy disputes, yet permit nations
greater freedom to adopt protectionist measures. Even so, the American Congress refused
ratification, the result of a coalition of free trade purists who thought the agreement too illiberal
and isolationists who thought it too internationalist. Thus, the tariff reduction negotiations of the
skeletal GATT, intended as an interim measure until the ITO could commence operations, became
the only instrument for regulating global trade. The result was globalization with relatively little
active involvement by either the U.S. or an international institution. Subsequently, the system was
to drift further from the compromises necessary for its founding and closer to the American vision
of proper (that is, minimal) economic management.
Changes in American policy
To the extent that the modestly internationalist position of the U.S. in Bretton Woods
could be reconciled with the role expectations of a hegemon, American policy changes since then
make clear that it was a temporary aberration from traditional practice. Motivated since the 1970s
by its rising vulnerability to trade competitors and its changing pattern of comparative advantage,
American policy has become increasingly narrowly self-interested. The U.S. has become less
attentive to matters of global system structure, instead pursuing its goals through aggressive
unilateralism and regionalism. Even when actively engaged, its multilateral agenda is now less
likely to champion initiatives justified by global welfare considerations, particularly if they appear
to require sacrifice of more immediate national goals or ideological purity. Most telling is the
American emphasis upon liberalization of capital markets -- where the U.S. comparative
advantage remains dominant -- even though the theoretical case is much stronger for free trade in
goods markets and evidence continues to accumulate that excessive capital flows have become
injurious to global welfare. The American neglect of systemic concerns has accelerated in recent
years because its global leadership had always been sustained by the cold war image that
international architecture was required to maintain its national security. The end of the Cold War
allowed the U.S. to return to its historic propensity to seek a naive combination of economic
benefits but political disengagement best exemplified by George Washington in his Farewell
Address: "The great rule of conduct for us in regard to foreign nations is, in extending our
commercial relations to have with them [the nations of Europe] as little political connection as
possible."
Aggressive unilateralism
As the U.S. stake in the global economy has grown -- trade levels as a percentage of GDP have nearly tripled since the immediate post-war period, for example -- both threats and opportunities have increased. American attempts to minimize the former while maximizing the latter have required a dual strategy. U.S. efforts to promote opportunities for American exporters and foreign investors remain concentrated in its multilateral drive for a global system free of barriers, while its unilateral and bilateral policies have increasingly erected such barriers to protect American firms that compete with imports. The U.S. justifies its unilateral actions as consistent with its systemic philosophy because they are designed to compensate for the unfair trade practices of others, but other nations have criticized this pattern as hypocritical, especially because the U.S. has resisted the creation of more binding trade dispute resolution mechanisms.
While American tariff rates for most favored nations have remained low, non-tariff barriers
(NTBs) targeted against particular nations have risen. They have taken several forms, some fully
in accord with GATT rules and even consistent with liberal principles. Section 201 of the Trade
Reform Act of 1974 implemented GATT's article 19 escape clause, permitting nations to suspend
tariff reductions for industries suffering from sudden increases in imports, regardless of cause.
This escape clause has not been frequently used, no doubt because it undermines the American
case for systemic liberalism. The U.S. has felt more free to employ Section 301 (and its extension
in the 1988 Trade Act dubbed "Super 301") because it is designed to target particular countries
found to be engaging in "unjustifiable, unreasonable or discriminatory" trading practices. It
authorizes countervailing duties to offset dumping by foreign manufacturers or subsidies by
foreign governments. As such, these actions can be squared with the idea of "fair trade" even if
their consistency with "free trade" is more dubious.
Competitors object to such an approach for many reasons. They contend that these
actions are often invoked for purely protectionist purposes, including the desire to deter sharp
competition for the American market by threatening successful competitors with the rigors of the
U.S. legal process and potential retaliation. They resent the extension of American domestic
principles to the international arena through extra-territoriality and ideological hegemony,
especially because "the Anglo-American view has taken on a moral tone.... If a country disagrees
with the Anglo-American axioms, it doesn't just disagree -- it is a cheater."(9) Further, it has
become common for the U.S. to threaten use of such "fair trade" actions in order to require
competitors to "voluntarily" reduce exports through voluntary export restraints (VERs), the most
prominent of which was the 1980s agreement that restricted the import of Japanese autos.
Moreover, it is not easy to predict when these actions will be invoked.(10) This has led some to
conclude that "the greatest potential for the erosion of multilateralism lies in the ability of the
powerful to heavy-ride rather than in the small and weak to free-ride."(11) By playing on the
ambiguity of "free trade" and "fair trade", these policies have enabled the U.S. to champion free
trade and deny its disruptive impact, yet simultaneously protect its most vulnerable industries.
The rise of regionalism
A second dimension of U.S. trade policy can be seen in a similarly ambivalent light. For
the past decade, the United States has displayed a tolerance -- perhaps even a preference -- for
regional trade systems. The clearest example is the Canada-United States Free Trade Area, which
quickly evolved into the North America Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA). Many liberal critics
saw this as a rejection of multilateralism and a dangerous step toward regional trade blocs
eventually bound to compete along mercantilist lines. Adding to these worries was American
encouragement of various Pacific Rim initiatives and continuing pressure by the Clinton
Administration to extend NAFTA throughout the Western Hemisphere as the Free Trade Area of
the Americas (FTAA).(12)
In contrast, the U.S. contends that NAFTA and FTAA represent an affirmation of its
hegemonic role of cajoling and bullying others to support multilateral liberalism -- because
NAFTA was a bargaining ploy to counter regionalism in Europe and thus re-energize the then-languishing Uruguay Round of GATT talks. NAFTA may have had that effect, but it also
demonstrated that the U.S. is far more satisfied with regional schemes than the mythical hegemon
of HST.
In fact, these regional agreements create liberalization structured along the lines favored
by the American vision but blocked at the global level by competing European perspectives.
NAFTA, which lacks not only a secretariat but even an identifiable physical location, embodies
the American ideal of a regime without institutions.(13) It also contrasts dramatically with the rich
tapestry woven of the EU's multiple agencies, which are meant to mitigate the effects of
liberalization and thus facilitate its extension and deepening. The U.S. remains intolerant of extra-national constraints, especially if they challenge America's vision of liberalization without side
effects.
The multilateral agenda
As U.S. dominance has eroded, America's willingness to ignore its own interests in
fashioning global policies has faded with it. The U.S. continues to promote liberalism, but mostly
in those areas in which American economic interests are directly involved. Only agriculture
became a real priority among producer-consumer talks in the Uruguay Round, in part because the
U.S. has become more reliant on financial flows than trade competitiveness. Thus, even while
trade barriers of major interest to less developed nations remain unresolved, U.S. energies in
GATT/WTO have been directed to auxiliary issues such as trade-related investment measures
(TRIMs), the protection of intellectual property rights, and trade in services.
With its advantages in financial services intact, the U.S. has been especially active in
promoting capital liberalization. One proposal would amend the IMF's charter to make the
liberalization of capital movements one of the purposes of the Fund and extend its jurisdiction to
supervise restrictions on capital flows. Another was the abortive effort to enact a Multilateral
Agreement on Investment (MAI), the centerpiece of which was the quintessential American
position that foreign investors should be guaranteed national treatment -- that is, virtually all
national restrictions on foreign direct investment should be prohibited. At least in the short term,
such liberalization would no doubt benefit MNCs, whose political influence, already strong in the
U.S. because of its unusual pattern of class relations, has grown further in recent years. Without
an institutional locus for working class solidarity -- American labor prefers the moniker of middle
class -- the interests of multinational capital have seldom been explicitly challenged. Initiatives
favorable to capital have also been aided by the breathtaking speed of further class transformation
in American society, driven by the decline of manufacturing, the rise of the white-collar service
sector and high technology, and, especially, the widespread distribution of equity issues through
401-K and mutual funds. The capitalist class has expanded -- more than a third of American
households now own stock -- while the decline in manufacturing has shrunk the mobilizable
working class.
The American vision
Even in the face of increasing evidence of its flaws, the U.S. remains committed to a
global system in line with its unique ideological vision -- liberalism supported by a very sparse
institutional structure to mitigate the adverse consequences of the globalization it produces. The
dilemma, faced squarely at Bretton Woods but neglected since, is put most plainly by a leading
proponent of globalization: "the most serious challenge for the world economy in the years ahead
lies in making globalization compatible with domestic social and political stability -- or to put it
even more directly, in ensuring that international economic integration does not contribute to
domestic social disintegration."(14) The threat arises from the significant distributional
consequences that attend massive trade and capital flows. Immediate dislocations (15) create
tensions and contribute strongly to the politically and socially divisive income inequality that has
been well documented in recent years. Furthermore, globalization engenders conflict over
domestic norms and the social institutions that embody them, including the potential for a "race to
the bottom" in labor standards and the environment.
None of these problems need undermine the case for global liberalization, however,
because most admit of governmental amelioration. Indeed, that is precisely the direction taken by
"the compromise of embedded liberalism" in the Bretton Woods era: "societies were asked to
embrace the change and dislocation attending international liberalization. In turn, liberalization
and its effects were cushioned by the newly acquired domestic economic and social policy roles of
governments".(16) Over the longer term, however, the unencumbered capital mobility of
contemporary globalization affords an exit option to capital owners that gives them
unprecedented bargaining leverage over nation-bound actors. Workers face declines in wages,
benefits, and working conditions and suffer the costs of increasing insecurity. Meanwhile, the
difficulty of taxing footloose capital severely undermines the capacity of governments to provide
social insurance or, indeed, to raise the revenues required to address any of the problems
exacerbated by globalization. Further, regulation to advance environmental or other social goals
becomes increasingly infeasible.
When the ability of national governments to cope with such problems has been sharply
reduced, one option is to augment national capacities with international ones. Another is to free
governments to balance these pressures as they see fit and even to facilitate their choice. GATT's
escape clause could be reinvigorated and antidumping mechanisms more explicitly monitored, for
example. If the IMF and World Bank were to encourage social insurance instead of demanding
austerity, government pull-backs from the intolerably harsh discipline of the so-called Washington
Consensus could be avoided. The role of these international financial institutions in dictating
policy is widely seen as undemocratic, especially since the privatization urged as part of the
Washington Consensus moves power from elected and accountable public officials to unelected,
unaccountable, foreign actors. Instead, the contemporary system has bound nations even more
tightly to liberal orthodoxy and contributed further to the crisis of political legitimacy unleashed
when governments are unable to insulate their citizens from the effects of global markets. It is
significant that the last attempt to so submerge alternative values to market discipline occurred
earlier in this century in the context of much less democratic polities.
The Asian currency crisis demonstrates what may be the most significant weakness of the
current system's devotion to capital mobility -- the monetary pressures that arise from the
Mundell-Fleming constraint that a nation cannot simultaneously achieve the three goals of capital
mobility, exchange rate stability, and monetary policy autonomy. Fidelity to the first of these is
enforced by both World Bank/IMF policy and the power of capital markets themselves to demand
the freedom to engage in capital flight as a condition for not exercising that right. States forced
to choose between the remaining two goals must hope that domestic economic and political needs
do not require the exercise of real autonomy and that exchange rate volatility does not escalate
beyond the tolerable. When the foreign exchange reserves of even the largest and most powerful
economies are inadequate to appreciably move the exchange rate through direct intervention, and
where the absence of a central institution to perform that role leaves domestic economies to adjust
very painfully to rapid movements of capital, an attentive hegemon might consider weakening the
forces of global finance. The U.S., however, cannot empathize with the complex effects of
exchange rate movements on other nations because its own small foreign sector transmits so few
impacts on price levels or output. Furthermore, capital controls threaten the interests of the
MNC, one of the few powerful American actors that relies heavily on the global economy.
Prominent alternatives exist. Provision could be made to exchange information to restrict
tax-strategies available to MNCs. The Tobin Tax proposed by economist James Tobin would tax
foreign exchange transactions, both to raise funds to support international efforts and to reduce
the appeal of the destabilizing short-term capital flows that have been implicated in economic
crises in East Asia and Latin America. The capital controls that have been used successfully in
otherwise liberal economies like Chile could be countenanced. The EU with its Social Charter
and a host of other policies and procedures enacted in recognition that such pressures represent
possible impediments to future liberalization demonstrate again that greater regulation can go
hand in hand with greater liberalization of trade. The funding available for crisis management
could be enhanced.
Instead, the U.S. has retreated from even its tepid style of leadership. While the global financial system appeared poised on the brink of collapse in the fall of 1998, disappointment with the IMF's management of the Asian crisis led the isolationist American Congress to seek the demise of the IMF rather than to alter either its policies or the liberal system as a whole.(17) They refused to fund an extension of the IMF and also refused to make good on more than $1 billion in back dues owed to the UN. Worse yet for the image of a benign hegemon, they have offered to meet financial obligations to the UN only in return for acquiring veto power with respect to the reproductive health agendas of all UN constituents (e.g. barring any mention of abortion). As Diana Tussie notes, "The United States has often interpreted a rule-based order to mean the extension of American rules and procedures to the rest of the world."(18)
It is arguable whether the unresponsive of American policy toward the costs implicit in
accelerating globalization results more from design or neglect. Two sets of explanations -- one
centered on isolationism and the other on a striking narrowness of strategic vision -- converge.
Certainly, the American image of a successful international economic system is decidedly less
regulated and institutionalized than others. In line with standard liberal theory, it seeks only to
decrease national governmental control of cross-border transactions, confident that the resulting
flows will increase prosperity. When problems arise (as in Mexico, Southeast Asia, and Russia),
it is content with ad hoc responses that maintain hegemonic autonomy rather than advancing
global institutional authority.
It is also true that the U.S. is poorly positioned to design ways of resolving or coping with
costs of globalization it does not feel. The U.S. has little experience with ameliorating trade-induced dislocations, unlike Europe, where generous welfare provisions have long complimented
protectionism to afford security to the working class and regionalism has eased the pressures on
the national state. Indeed, the division of authority between levels of government makes it
difficult for the U.S. to integrate trade policy, which is enacted by the Federal government, and
welfare and education policy, which are largely functions of state and local government. On the
finance side, the U.S. is even less familiar with the challenges of coping with volatile and
uncomfortable capital flows that have lately plagued developing countries.
Contemporary globalization: a patchwork of inadequate governance
A regime committed to this neo-liberal brand of globalization has severe limitations, most
notably that it is less stable than one built to withstand the predictable economic and political
forces that emerge within any under-regulated system. This involves not only such "economic"
forces as destabilizing capital flows but "political" forces that have not been accommodated in
system creation (like dissenting nations and sub-national interests.) Instead of exploring
alternatives, the U.S. has hoped to silence dissenters by portraying globalism as natural, inevitable,
and irreversible. To the contrary, the 1920s demonstrate that when globalization is seen as a
source of problems by citizens not convinced of its benefits, it can be reversed with breathtaking
speed. Or, as Rodrik notes, "social disintegration is not a spectator sport -- those on the sidelines
also get splashed with mud from the field."(19)
In short, the explanation for recent evolution of the system lies in the peculiar character of
American hegemony. Only an ideological hegemon would fail to see the need for more aggressive
action and only an isolationist one would fail to act on it. As a result, it appears that the gravest
threat to the globalization goal lies not in diminished American hegemony, but rather in continuing
implementation of America's peculiar vision of its hegemonic role.
Suggested Readings
Block, Fred L. The Origins of International Economic Disorder. Berkeley: University of California Press, 1977.
Blumenthal, Sidney. "The Return of the Repressed: Anti-Internationalism and the American Right," World Policy
Journal, 12 (1995), pp. 1-13.
Cline, William R. Trade and Income Distribution. Washington: Institute for International Economics, 1997.
Crabb, Cecil. Policy-Makers and Critics. New York: Praeger Publishers, 1976.
Goldstein, Judith. "Ideas, Institutions, and American Trade Policy," International Organization 42, 1 (1988): pp.
179-217
Helleiner, Gerald. "Transnational Enterprises and the New Political Economy of U.S. Trade Policy," Oxford
Economic Papers 29, 1 (1977).
Kindleberger, Charles. The World in Depression 1929-39. Berkeley: University of California Press, 1973.
Kennedy, Paul. "The (Relative) Decline of America," Atlantic Monthly, August 1987: pp. 29-38.
Pauly, Louis. Who Elected the Bankers? Surveillance and Control in the World Economy. Ithaca: Cornell
University Press, 1997.
Polanyi, Karl. The Great Transformation. New York: Reinhart, 1944.
Rogowski, Ronald. "Political Cleavages and Changing Exposure to Trade," American Political Science Review 81, 4 (1987), pp. 1121-1137.
1. Robert Gilpin, The Political Economy of International Relations (Princeton, New Jersey: Princeton University Press, 1987), pp. 72-92.
2. John Ruggie, "International Regimes, Transactions, and Change: Embedded Liberalism in the Postwar Economic Order," International Organization 36: 382.
3. Ruggie, p. 382. For the generally unregulated character of "Anglo-Saxon" capitalism, see James Fallows, "How the World Works," The Atlantic Monthly, December 1993, pp. 61-87.
4. Evidence that the United States eschewed global leadership for half a century after its economic dominance entitled it to such a role includes the refusal to join the League of Nations and to cooperate at the World Economic Conference in London in 1933. The persistence of this attitude was demonstrated in the 1970s when President Nixon unilaterally dissolved the fixed-rate monetary order that threatened American policy autonomy.
5. Exports account for slightly over 10% of U.S. GNP, roughly a third of the European average. The U.S. has relied on foreign capital to balance perpetual trade deficits but it has not been forced to alter policy to attract it.
6. "How the World Works", p. 65. His inclusion of Britain is clearly misplaced, except during the Thatcher period.
7. For an elaboration of this noteworthy phrase, see Ruggie, "International Regimes"
8. Ruggie, p. 399.
9. Fallows, p. 35.
10. Indeed, Canadian enthusiasm for CUSTA owed much to its binational trade dispute resolution panels, which could block arbitrary American actions.
11. Diana Tussie, "Multilateralism Revisited in a Globalizing World Economy," Mershon International Studies Review 42 (1998), p. 190.
12. Congressional opposition, motivated by nationalist and protectionist sentiment, blocked the latter by refusing to grant "fast track" authority to negotiate agreements exempt from legislative amendment.
13. Without a class-based system of political representation, the best organized American opposition to such agreements has come from progressive organizations like environmental groups. They have joined with elements of the right to emphasize the potential threats to national autonomy represented by the WTO and NAFTA's binational dispute resolution panels rather than distributional consequences.
14. Dani Rodrik, "Has Globalization Gone Too Far?" (Washington: Institute for International Economics, 1997), p. 2.
15. For example, "under typical parameters, lowering of a trade restriction will result in $5 or more of income being shuffled among different groups for every $1 of net gain." Rodrik, p. 30.
16. John Ruggie, "At Home Abroad, Abroad at Home: International Liberalization and Domestic Stability in the New World Economy," Millennium: Journal of International Studies 24, 3: 508.
17. Designing a more humane globalization requires a combination of attributes not to be found in Congress where internationalists are almost exclusively liberal whereas opponents of the market are both protectionist and isolationist.
18. Tussie, p. 189.
19. Rodrik, p. 7.